Skip to main content
Article
A test of two skew models to explain cooperative breeding.
USF St. Petersburg campus Faculty Publications
  • Deby L. Cassill
  • Indira Kuriachan
  • S. Bradleigh Vinson
SelectedWorks Author Profiles:

Deby L. Cassill

Document Type
Article
Publication Date
2007
Disciplines
Abstract

Two competing models, reproductive skew and skew selection, have been constructed to explain the evolution of cooperation among unrelated breeders. Reproductive skew is a trade-off model that assumes breeding occurs under scarce resource conditions. One breeder gains units of fecundity at the expense of other breeders during aggressive, altruistic or tug-of-war transactions. After joining, the distribution of fecundity among breeders shifts from symmetrical to asymmetrical. In contrast, skew selection is a surplus model that assumes breeding occurs during a springtime glut. Skew selection assumes that fecundity among breeders is initially asymmetrical and that joining reduces the asymmetry of fecundity. This paper reports findings from a breeding experiment on the fire ant, Solenopsis invicta, which supported skew selection rather than reproductive skew. Joining was a win-win strategy for alpha and beta breeders; beta breeders gained within-group survival benefits; alpha breeders gained between-group survival benefits. In summary, skew selection extends Darwin's theory of natural selection by revealing the self-interested core of cooperative breeding.

Comments
Abstract only. Full-text article is available only through licensed access provided by the publisher. Published in Journal of Bioeconomics, 9,19-37. doi: 10.1007/s10818-007-9012-7 Members of the USF System may access the full-text of the article through the authenticated link provided.
Language
en_US
Publisher
Springer Verlag
Creative Commons License
Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-No Derivative Works 4.0
Citation Information
Cassill, D.L., Kuriachan, I., & Vinson, S. B. (2007). A test of two skew models to explain cooperative breeding. Journal of Bioeconomics, 9,19-37. doi: 10.1007/s10818-007-9012-7